52 pages 1 hour read

The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money

Nonfiction | Book | Adult | Published in 1935

A modern alternative to SparkNotes and CliffsNotes, SuperSummary offers high-quality Study Guides with detailed chapter summaries and analysis of major themes, characters, and more.

Part 4Chapter Summaries & Analyses

Part 4: “Book IV: The Inducement to Invest”

Part 4, Chapter 11 Summary: “The Marginal Efficiency of Capital”

Keynes’s concept of the marginal efficiency of capital is vital to understanding why businesses decide to invest. He defines the marginal efficiency of capital as the rate of discount that makes the present value of an asset’s expected future returns exactly equal its current supply price, or the cost of producing a new unit of that asset. Investing in new capital will continue until the marginal efficiency of capital aligns with the prevailing interest rate.

Keynes emphasizes that this marginal efficiency depends on expectations about future yields and potential changes in production costs. Factors like new technology or anticipated shifts in wage levels can shift the investment demand schedule by altering projected returns. Unlike a purely static idea of capital returns, the notion of marginal efficiency captures the forward-looking nature of investing. He also draws attention to borrower’s risk versus lender’s risk, explaining how uncertainty over whether returns will materialize can depress overall investment appetite. Finally, Keynes underlines the role of expectations, noting that investment hinges more on forecasts of future profitability than on present yields alone. This dynamic view of how capital decisions link today’s economy with tomorrow’s conditions is core to his broader argument.

Part 4, Chapter 12 Summary: “The State of Long-Term Expectation”

Keynes explores how investors form long-term expectations about prospective returns on capital assets and why these expectations can be extremely fragile. Many economic decisions about future investment rely on a shaky foundation: No one can be certain about what conditions—consumer demands, market competition, or technological advancements—will prevail several years hence. Historically, investments were often undertaken by individual entrepreneurs fueled by optimism rather than precise calculation. In modern markets, however, the widespread ability to buy and sell shares daily—coupled with mass psychology—has introduced new volatility.

Keynes holds that “the state of confidence” (91), though difficult to measure rigorously, is central to investment decisions. Stock market prices, while appearing to provide continuous valuations, can be swayed by speculative behavior as investors anticipate short-term shifts in market sentiment rather than base their choices on a reasoned forecast of an asset’s long-run yield. This casino-like quality of modern exchanges can cause harmful cycles of booms and busts when enterprise is overshadowed by speculative fervor.

Despite this precariousness, certain mitigating factors exist, such as contractual guarantees in utility investments, or government-led projects where the social good is paramount over exact profitability. Keynes concludes by emphasizing that interest rates alone cannot ensure adequate, stable investment. He foresees a growing role for government in directly coordinating capital outlays to counteract the inevitable uncertainties of private long-term expectation.

Part 4, Chapter 13 Summary: “The General Theory of the Rate of Interest”

Keynes defines the rate of interest as a reward for relinquishing liquidity rather than as a straightforward return to saving. He distinguishes between two psychological components of time-preference: the propensity to consume, which decides how much income is reserved for future use, and the preference for liquidity, which determines how people choose to hold that reserved portion—either in cash or in interest-bearing assets. According to Keynes, the rate of interest results from balancing the supply of money with the public’s overall desire for holding cash. If people prefer to keep their resources liquid, the rate of interest has to rise to make parting with money more attractive. Conversely, if liquidity-preference weakens, the interest rate falls. Changes in long-term interest rates thus depend not just on how much people want to save, but on how strong their desire is to remain liquid given uncertainties about future prices or rates. This nuance helps explain why an increase in money supply does not automatically lower interest rates—public confidence and expectations also play a critical role in determining how eagerly people exchange cash for assets offering returns.

Part 4, Chapter 14 Summary: “The Classical Theory of the Rate of Interest”

Keynes critiques classical economic theory’s contention that the rate of interest equilibrates saving and investment. Under this view, interest is viewed as the price of investable resources, ensuring that the amount saved (supply) matches the amount invested (demand). Keynes points out that, despite being widespread, this notion fails to explain how interest is actually determined in a monetary economy.

He argues that saving and investment are merely outcomes that must equal each other once all decisions in the economy are made; they are not themselves the forces fixing the interest rate. Instead, the interest rate results from the interplay of people’s desire for liquidity—liquidity preference—and the available money supply. Classical analysis neglects the crucial fact that changes in aggregate income can alter both saving and investment, so one cannot treat the amount to be saved as fixed while shifting the demand for capital. This oversight leads to a flawed conclusion that the rate of interest automatically adjusts to any new balance of saving and investment. Keynes underscores that if the central bank or policy authority adjusts the money supply, it can influence the interest rate; by contrast, classical theory implies that money policy is largely irrelevant in establishing a “natural” market rate. Ultimately, Keynes’s criticism highlights that recognizing income fluctuations and liquidity-preference is indispensable to understanding why the rate of interest settles where it does.

Part 4, Chapter 15 Summary: “The Psychological and Business Incentives to Liquidity”

Keynes refines his theory of liquidity preference by categorizing the motives behind why individuals and businesses hold cash. Beyond the immediate transactions motive (covering day-to-day income and business costs) and the precautionary motive (guarding against future uncertainties), he highlights a third, important factor: the speculative motive. According to Keynes, people hold money in anticipation that interest rates could shift, rendering bond holdings either profitable or risky. The combined desire for cash from these three motives interacts with the available money supply to shape the market rate of interest.

Keynes emphasizes that, while money demanded for transactions and precautionary purposes is relatively stable (closely linked to income and business volume), the speculative demand is more elastic and strongly influences monetary policy effectiveness. Central banks, through open-market operations, can lower or raise bond prices and thus interest rates—but only up to a point. If investors collectively fear a rise in rates or deem rates too low, they may hold onto cash despite attempts to flood the market with liquidity. Consequently, the interest rate becomes a phenomenon sustained by collective expectations. Whether rates drop enough to stimulate new investments depends not just on policy, but also on whether the public believes in the durability of low rates, underscoring the psychological and social underpinnings of Keynes’s liquidity preference framework.

Part 4, Chapter 16 Summary: “Sundry Observations on the Nature of Capital”

Keynes discusses how individual acts of saving do not necessarily spur equivalent demand for future goods. Unlike a direct order for delayed consumption, general saving simply withdraws current spending from the economy without creating a guaranteed offsetting demand for future consumption. This can lower overall effective demand, thereby curbing both consumption-related industries and new investment if it also depresses the marginal efficiency of capital.

Keynes explains that capital’s value stems from its scarcity—if it becomes overly abundant, its marginal efficiency can drop to zero. Normally, interest rates adjust to balance saving and investment, but institutional and psychological factors often prevent rates from declining sufficiently. In such cases, forced saving can accumulate wealth to a point that undermines full employment. He envisions a scenario where, with proper monetary and social policies, the marginal efficiency of capital gradually falls toward zero, turning capitalist economies quasi-stationary and eliminating the rentier class whose income derives largely from accumulated wealth rather than productive work. However, uncertainties about future yields and the existence of risk premiums mean there can still be returns on specific investments, ensuring that some entrepreneurial activity and speculative behavior remains.

Part 4, Chapter 17 Summary: “The Essential Properties of Interest and Money”

Keynes explores why the money-rate of interest exerts a uniquely powerful influence on economic activity, contrasting it with other “own-rates” of interest (e.g. the wheat-rate of interest). Any durable asset can be measured in terms of its own-rate, defined by its expected yield, minus carrying costs, plus a liquidity-premium. Yet money, unlike other commodities, usually has: 1) almost no carrying costs and 2) a high liquidity-premium, making its effective rate of interest comparatively unresponsive to supply increases.

Keynes argues that money’s inelasticity of production prevents entrepreneurs from easily manufacturing additional money if its value (and hence its interest) rises. Further, its zero (or near-zero) elasticity of substitution means that as its price climbs, few stand ready to switch into another asset. These features allow money to become a bottomless sink of purchasing power. Because of this, a rise in the money-rate of interest halts new investment in more easily produced goods (e.g., houses, wheat) but does not stimulate output of money itself. Consequently, the money-rate often sets an upper bound for growth, since the marginal efficiency of newly produced capital must exceed that money-rate to be profitable.

He extends this notion by showing that if another commodity, such as wheat, were to become the standard of value, the same problem would arise if wheat also could be produced or substituted easily. Ultimately, classical notions of a unique “natural” rate of interest, set by saving and investment alone, ignore the fact that every level of employment and output can have a different natural rate. Instead, modern economies remain anchored by a money whose rate of interest tends to stick above what’s needed for full employment. Government monetary policies can mitigate this, but must contend with people’s strong desire to hold money, given its unrivaled liquidity and negligible costs.

Part 4, Chapter 18 Summary: “The General Theory of Employment Re-Stated”

Keynes restates his main argument regarding employment determination. He outlines how certain factors—like existing technology, labor supply, consumer habits, and social structures—remain relatively fixed, while three independent variables guide economic outcomes: the propensity to consume, the marginal efficiency of capital, and the interest rate. These variables shape investment, which, through the multiplier effect, dictates levels of employment and aggregate income. In equilibrium, new capital investment will proceed up to the point where its marginal efficiency matches the prevailing interest rate, after which additional output and jobs no longer appear profitable. Keynes further emphasizes the role of stability conditions—such as a moderately sized multiplier, elasticity in capital production, and “sticky” wages—in preventing the economy from spiraling into extreme booms or collapses. Yet these conditions also allow chronic underemployment to persist, as neither automatic market forces nor flexible wages necessarily drive output up to full employment. Hence, the chapter stresses that the system, while often resting in a stable, suboptimal position, is not bound by any immutable law. Policymakers can influence fundamental psychological and institutional factors—particularly through monetary and fiscal actions—to shift employment and income toward more satisfactory outcomes.

Part 4 Analysis

Keynes devotes this extensive section to exploring how investment decisions take shape within an uncertain future, positioning this inquiry as the core of his broader theory. He places special emphasis on the idea that firms commit resources today based on expected yields, rather than on fixed or static conditions. This marks a shift from classical views that treat investment like a straightforward equation of saving and lending: Instead, Keynes contends that the long-term profitability of capital goods depends upon unpredictable variables, including shifts in technology and consumer demand. By making the notion of forward-looking expectations pivotal, he reinforces the idea that mere alignment of costs and present-day returns does not suffice to spur continued growth.

Central to his argument is the marginal efficiency of capital, which Keynes defines as the discounted value of an asset’s anticipated stream of future earnings relative to its cost of production. Once businesses sense that these prospective returns fall below the interest they must pay or forego, they see little reason to extend new investment. This perspective highlights The Power of Aggregate Demand when entrepreneurs doubt the economy’s capacity to purchase their output at profitable prices. Although capital accumulation can accelerate rapidly when earnings prospects are high, it stalls just as easily if firms become skeptical about future consumption. Keynes thereby shows how the scale of investment depends at least as much on shifting confidence in tomorrow’s markets as on the purely numerical relation between saving and lending.

Yet expectations are not simply rational projections; they are intertwined with the human tendency toward optimism or fear. Keynes’s famous point that “when the capital development of a country becomes a by-product of the activities of a casino, the job is likely to be ill-done” (97) underscores his warning that speculation and herd behavior often override sober calculation. Businesses that might otherwise invest carefully in capital improvements can get swept up in stock market surges or panics, diverting resources away from genuinely productive uses. This dynamic reflects the Psychological Underpinnings of Economic Behavior, as the collective mood of investors inflames or undercuts what, on paper, appear to be well-grounded projections of future growth. Traditional economic models cannot fully explain sudden collapses in venture financing or abrupt booms if they ignore how easily these so-called “animal spirits” can shift the entire trajectory of capital formation.

Another key innovation is Keynes’s reinterpretation of the interest rate as a reward for sacrificing liquidity, rather than as a simple return to saving: “The rate of interest is […] the reward for parting with liquidity for a specified period” (102). If people collectively prefer to hold money—out of caution or in the hope of buying assets later at lower prices—the interest rate must rise to entice them to lend or invest. Conversely, if confidence grows that bonds or other instruments will prove profitable, the interest rate can decline without unleashing instant inflation. This idea further shapes how liquidity preference interacts with the marginal efficiency of capital to determine whether new projects move forward. Keynes thus contradicts the classical premise that interest naturally balances saving and investment: He insists it emerges from how individuals weigh the advantages of holding cash against the uncertain returns of tying up funds in long-term capital.

The interplay of these forces—marginal efficiency, liquidity preference, and fickle sentiment—leads Keynes to conclude that economies can languish at less-than-full employment for extended periods. Businesses may withhold investment if they fear low demand, while would-be savers resist parting with liquidity if they suspect unstable markets. Hence, Government Intervention and the Public Sector’s Role often become necessary to bolster confidence, expand money supply, or directly invest in projects when private decision-makers hesitate. Book 4 crystallizes how these intertwined factors shape real-world outcomes: Rather than gravitating automatically to an optimal equilibrium, modern economies need deliberate policy guidance to sustain investment, tame speculation, and harness a steady outlook for the future.

blurred text
blurred text
blurred text
blurred text
Unlock IconUnlock all 52 pages of this Study Guide

Plus, gain access to 9,100+ more expert-written Study Guides.

Including features:

+ Mobile App
+ Printable PDF
+ Literary AI Tools